A Win for Old School Economics
Economics has been called the dismal science for decades. The somewhat newer slight (still decades old) led to the birth of Behavioral Economics whose guardians believe stodgy, old, Econ 101 principles of supply and demand and rational actors making rational cost/benefit choices fails to explain reality.
Some of that’s true though the BE truthers out there have their own crisis of confidence dubbed ‘replication crisis’. If all you have is a hammer, everything’s a nail, regardless of hammer type.
Readers should note, I am part of two behavioral science agencies. Behavioral science does not = behavioral economics. The latter is a subset of the former. The former is a multidisciplinary field that provides a more complete set of tools.
Our BS approach (yes, that acronym is rimshot worthy) also doesn’t kick old school Econ 101 to the curb. And for good reason. There are three principles so far unbeaten in our fundraising world that I was reminded of while reading a novel analysis of scientific papers.
- All piles of profit eventually go to zero. This is a supply/demand 101 truism. New entrants go into markets/channels/opportunities where money is being made. Those new entrants compete, commoditize and drive the margin to zero or nearly so. Costs going up and yields going down.
Sound familiar doesn’t it. Particularly if you do canvassing in mature European markets or direct mail in the US? It turns out the same thing happens everywhere, even in the scientific paper publishing business. It’s all volume, all the time. The number of journals and publications and submissions grows by leaps and bounds trying to suck up the profit of subscriptions and tenure (for researchers).
- Diminishing returns always happens. “Marginal utility” –what a wonky Econ term. It means increasing volume of anything will coincide with getting less and less return. If you mail 5 times and make 100k you will not make 200k if you double it to 10 mailings. In the scientific publishing arms race it turns out volume is also the metric of choice. The gateway drug there is policy aimed at increasing the quantity of scientists, research funding and scientific output, which is measured, in part, by the number of papers published. It turns out, the marginal increase to knowledge and innovation is minimal. Hammer and nail never looked so good.
- Copy-catting rules the day in a volume world. You won’t find this in the Econ books as such but it still holds because of old-school, economic principles. The profit maximizer’s best path to profit is copying what has already been done. This lowers cost and short-term risk, both of which increase short-term profit. The problem is innovation dies or is really, really slow to be birthed. How about that nickel package? Or the faux petition or faux survey or the F2F leave-behind or welcome pack or newsletter? The scientific journal community behaves similarly. It turns out the best (maybe only) way to get published is by lots of citations and, better yet, citing that which has already been cited. Guess what that produces? More papers saying essentially the same thing.
I’m closing by sharing the (slightly edited) closing remarks in the paper i was reading analyzing papers. I’ve made the obvious replacements to see if folks agree with the striking similarities.
The more-is-better, quantity metric-driven nature of today’s scientific (fundraising) enterprise may ironically retard fundamental progress in the largest scientific (fundraising) fields.
Reducing quantity may be impossible. Proscribing the number of annual publications (solicitations), shuttering journals (redundant organizations) and reducing the number of scientists (fundraisers) are hard-to-swallow policy prescriptions.
Still, some changes in how scholarship (fundraising) is conducted, disseminated, consumed, and rewarded may help accelerate fundamental progress in large fields of science (fundraising).
Reward and promotion systems, especially at the most prestigious institutions (charities), that eschew quantity measures and value fewer, deeper, more novel contributions could reduce the deluge while inspiring more innovative work.
Kevin
Flavorful. Well worth a mental chewing. Read it twice.
PS: The second reading was for the pleasure of the prose.
PPS: Then there was my 3rd read (your prose is crystal clear; my brain is not).
One small bugaboo caught my eye. The article says: “The profit maximizer’s best path to profit is copying what has already been done. This lowers cost and short-term risk, both of which increase short-term profit. The problem is innovation dies or is really, really slow to be birthed. How about that nickel package? Or the faux petition or faux survey or the F2F leave-behind or welcome pack or newsletter?”
Pity the newsletter.
It has struck me for the longest time that newsletters are poorly understood by those who don’t actually do them.
The assumption seems to be that ALL charity newsletters are created equal. Far from it: there are great ones, and there are resoundingly bad ones. Bad ones have been the rule, not the exception.
That observation goes back at least 15 years, when I had 60 or so charity newsletters spread out across my office. Most of them followed the same unlikely-to-succeed pattern: they celebrated the .org, not the donor. And they devoted valuable front-page space to some wretched bit of sizzle-lacking PR typically called “From the desk of the Executive Director….”
Good charity newsletters are major contributors.
The good ones make money (sometimes prompting HUGE amounts of EXTRA donated revenue; I saw a print newsletter created during the pandemic consistently net $400,000 per mailing). And they foster tribe: they flatter and inform and entertain and deliver a strong sense of purpose to your true believers.
Most, though, are NOT good ones. By now, I’ve looked at hundreds. Many are determinedly self-promotional (pointless to the target reader). Most have no working knowledge of the fundamentals of journalism (REAL headlines, please). And far too many skimp on the donor love (though this is changing bit by bit as donor-centricity filters down from the top-performers to the copycats).
Tom, thanks for all the comments and self-torture of multiple reads no less… I think your points on newsletter are exactly our point in that the race to the middle (or bottom) is to mindlessly copy rather than taking some time to figure out what’s worth copying and why. Labeling something newsletter is not going to cut it, as if slapping that label on it bestows magical properties in and of itself.
Having migrated from the fundraising (direct mail w/CMS) arena to small business entrepreneurial arena, I see your point and raise you two. 1– The riches are in the niches. Look-alike large organizations are on their way out unless they are the one or two largest (AARP, e.g.) that have an Amazon like grip on their market. This is inherent Pareto optimality 80/20 as you point out. Tightly honing the message to market match holds the keys to the kingdom. And this usually means a smaller market and more copy testing. A record number of nonprofits have been founded in the past two years. Managing a nonprofit in this (digital first, entrepreneurial) environment takes a whole different set of skills then it did 20 years ago. Speaking of which, 2 — it’s not effective to think about “the sector.” That’s old school academic mush as you say. There’s no magic formula for moving forward, but a commitment to seeking the best thinkers, having better conversations, and applying what you learn will go a long way. Rogue economists are a good place to start. I particularly like Nicholas Taleb (Anti-fragile).